forbes.com
Mobile applications and services are overtaking the World
Wide Web for the key activities that we do on the Internet. Mobile is an
increasingly important part of any company’s marketing strategy, and developers
think mobile first when they design new Internet applications. In 2015
the app economy, the revenue driven through mobile apps and related activities, isexpected to reach as $100 billion. So what drives mobile innovation
and adoption? Here’s a review of the key academic theories.
In his book Innovator’s Dilemma Clay
Christiansensuggests that profits from established companies are a signal for
upstart firms to find disruptive innovation. This would explain the success of
WhatsApp, which disrupted a successful stream of SMS revenue by offering a free
over the top messaging service. He notes that successful firms are so
busy focusing on the valuable part of their business that they forget the
opportunities at the low end of the market. Similarly Joseph Schumpeter’screative
destruction is predicated on the idea that necessity creates
invention. Technology is an endless cycle of one paradigm toppling the
next. Just as the telephone eclipsed the telegraph, the mobile phone
eclipsed the landline phone.
Two other theories come from UC Berkeley professors
David Teece and Henry Chesbrough. Teece’s theory of complimentary
assets observe that an app by itself has no value. It needs to be
embedded with the complementary assets that give it value. For example the
digital personal assistant app Siri can’t be realized without an iPhone or a
high speed mobile network. The fact that more than half of the world’s 4G
connections are in North America enables a de factor digital market to many
users with advanced devices on advanced national networks.
Chesbrough, who coined the term open innovation, was
interested in how established firms such as IBM and Xerox could keep
innovating. He suggests that they need to look outside their walls to
find innovative partners. Interestingly WhatsApp leverages the global
Indian diaspora with a partnership with Indian mobile operators. Grandmothers,
who would never otherwise have a mobile broadband connection, now use
“zero-rated” versions of WhatsApp to keep in touch with their children
and grandchildren around the world. WhatsApp is not charged to the mobile
subscription data cap, but it’s the incentive needed to get the elderly to try
the Internet.
Zero-rating is just a fancy way to say that a sponsor
supports the delivery of a product or service, just like advertisements on
radio, TV, print or website. It’s a business model that has been around for a
century. Google zero-rates its searches with ads just as Facebook its social
network. Similarly on handsets, the device maker can license pre-loaded apps to
make their handsets more cool (think Angry Birds). Alternatively Google offers
the Android operating system for free to device makers in exchange for the
pre-installation of certain apps on the device.
There are other innovation theories such as Lemley and
Lessig’s end to end principle, the ability of an application to reach
any user. This theory is used as the basis of proposed regulation for net
neutrality, but the rise of app store optimization (ASO) challenges any idea
that the mobile Internet is neutral and that users simply find apps without any
mediation. Similar to search engine optimization (SEO), ASO is the
practice of making one’s mobile app findable for the target audience because
apps without marketing almost never find users.
For Everett Rogers, the most cited academic on this topic,
adoption of innovation is a social, not economic process. Anyone who has seen a
line outside the Apple Store on the day of a new release has seen the
motivation of what Rogers calls “early adopters”. Rogers introduced and refined
the Diffusion of Innovations bell curve in five subsequent
editions of his best-selling book.
There are many theories which could explain the
mobile app economy, and no one theory explains everything. However
policymakers are keen to boil down complex processes and systems to a simple
prescription, such as approve or prohibit X. For example earlier this year the
Chilean government banned zero-rating on mobile subscriptions, only to do an
about face shortly thereafter because citizens demanded zero-rated versions of
Wikipedia. It is strange that some want to ban zero rating, as they may be the
very partnerships we need to realize the app economy. It goes to show we should
be careful what we ban, especially that which we don’t understand.
No comments:
Post a Comment